Along
with fellow economic historian Robert W. Fogel, Douglass C.
North was awarded the 1993 Bank of Sweden Prize in Economic
Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel. North's award was remarkable
in at least one respect: where more recent winners of the
Nobel Prize in economics were predominately noted for their
technical and mathematical sophistication or their dedication
to "blackboard economics," North's award signaled the growing
influence of the New Institutional Economics - an interdisciplinary
school of thought that combines economics, law, history, sociology
and increasingly, as of late, cognitive science. Two years
earlier, the committee awarded Ronald Coase whose work explored
the significance of transaction costs and property rights
- analytic tools of New Institutional Economics.
Like
many economic historians, North asks: why do some nations
prosper while others fail miserably? Why do some economies
evolve over time and others fail to mature? What factors account
for development and progress? These questions beget others
such as: How well do we understand reality? How do beliefs
get formed? Who's beliefs matter and how do individual beliefs
aggregate into belief systems? How do they change?
North
suspects that the "the incentive structure embedded in institutions"
has a lot to say about these questions. In his efforts to
build a theory of economic change, North looks beyond neoclassical
economics, whose "elegant analytical tools cannot prescribe
policies that will induce development." Such tools say much
about supply and demand in a frictionless setting but they
can't explain why economies evolve.
"Institutions
form the incentive structure of a society and the political
and economic institutions, in consequence are the underlying
determinant of economic performance," he says. The metaphor
most often used by North and the NIE school is scaffolding.
According
to North, neoclassical economics' main conceit is that institutions
(which embody certain rules and constraints) and time (which
is ever changing or as North likes to say "non-ergodic") are
irrelevant to understanding economic growth. That is to say,
neoclassicists do not account for any scaffolding.
Some
neoclassicists may find this mildly controversial. They simply
don't think much about the fact that, for markets to flourish,
government at a minimum must clearly define property rights,
enforce contracts between individuals and parties, and enforce
the rule of law with an independent and credible judiciary.
North
takes his research project in a slightly different direction.
He insists on modifying the rationality assumption (sometimes
belief systems fail to empower man's dominance over physical
reality) and extending his analysis by adding the dimension
of time. Rational choice is sufficient for "evaluating opportunity
costs at the supermarket, but it is wildly incorrect when
it comes to making more complicated choices in a world of
incomplete information and of subjective models used to interpret
that incomplete information." Choices are often made even
in rational states of mind based on "non-rational" considerations.
The consequence of this hybrid choice is responsible for the
way we erect scaffolds (institutions and organizations, rules
and players) and as Friedrich Hayek showed us, test them for
error.
To
North, time is the embodiment not only of current experiences
but the cumulative experiences of the past that make up a
culture. Culture is the result of how societies perceive reality
and thus how we make choices. In taking his analysis close
to the periphery of cognitive science, North insists that
any incentive structure developed over time requires "a theory
of the way the mind perceives the world and its functioning
so that the institutions will provide those incentives."
In
setting out to explain economic change, North is actually
very modest. He doesn't come up with a unified theory of what
causes economic change; he knows that much empirical work
remains to be done on institutions. In the end, he suggests
even a limit to "adaptive efficiency." The ability of the
United States, for example, to reform and revise its institutions
(deregulation and tax reform come to mind) to solve specific
economic problems and promote growth is a good example of
adaptive efficiency. However, adaptive efficiency, sorely
lacking in the Soviet Union, may be of limited use to intractable
parts of the world.
When
it comes to understanding economic change we currently know
three phenomena. The quantity and quality of human beings
has improved remarkably (longer lifespan, better food and
medicine, greater consumption, more choices, and emigration).
Second, the stock of human knowledge has exponentially grown
to the point where we, unlike other species, have a tremendous
command over nature. Third, we know the importance of incentives
and how they are cultivated through patents, copyrights and
other laws.
North
maintains, "A complete theory of economic change would therefore
integrate theories of demographic, stock of knowledge, and
institutional change. We are far from having good theories
of any one of these three, much less of the three together
but we are making progress."
How
we make that progress is important and this is certainly a
tall order that extends beyond economics. But we can start
with what neo-classicists ignored in Adam Smith. We can explain
economic change and improve performance if we resolve four
stumbling blocks originally identified in Adam Smith's Wealth
of Nations.
1)
Successful societies know how to enable impersonal exchange.
A certain leap of faith is required to engage in business
with people you do not know. Wealth is realized only when
we can exploit the gains from large scale, 'impersonal' markets
where both parties trust a system of exchange.
2)
The specialization of knowledge. Knowledge has spillover effects
that don't fit nicely into a price system; some way must be
found to exploit rents from information. Entrepreneurs must
find a way to profit from their ability to cull disparate
pieces of information while governments need to foster the
"public goods" aspect of research and development. .
3)
Institutions must change to make sure to get the incentives
right.
4)
And markets require governments but "not just any government."
North wisely suggests that "institutions that limit the government
from preying on the market" are critical to improving performance.
History bears him out here.
Taken
together we might apply these prerequisites to a developing
country. Institutions, more broadly, the rules of the game,
must ensure that contracts be enforced between strangers willing
to engage in exchange, that institutions find ways such as
copyright and patents to dispense knowledge and that any gains
be protected by government, which must be restrained. The
United States and Western Europe appear to have a rough idea
of what it takes. Yet this property rights regime eludes post-Soviet
Russia
The
modern age has certainly thrown up challenges to economic
development; and so too will the revolution in life sciences.
As the low marginal costs of creating another publication,
song, software program and drug approach zero, such disruptive
technologies pose new challenges to any incentive system.
On
the other hand the development of open source software such
as Linux, the ability of the internet to move data at unimagined
speed and the fluidity of capital to flee where it is not
treated well certainly point to "new artifactual structures"
or property rights regimes. Who gets this right - in the face
of egalitarian and anti-free trade pressures - is poised for
success.
North
sees economists as hanging onto a body of theory that can't
explain economic change. He sees himself a heir to Hayek who
called for continuous trials in the face of ubiquitous uncertainty.
"Economists have the correct insight that economics is a theory
of choice. But to improve the human prospect we must understand
the sources of human decision making. That is a necessary
condition for human survival."
This
book is the result of a career long inquiry into the nature
of economic change. North provides us with a compelling case
that as the world becomes more complex we ought to find ways
to improve our institutions beyond what economic theory currently
offers. It is intellectually engrossing and should be of interest
to both scholars in both the hard and soft sciences. Understanding
the Process of Economic Change is a book for serious thinkers.
|